Understanding growth cycles
While volatility of growth has increased after the reforms, the basic
character of business cycles, post-Independence, has not changed.
September 13, 2012:
It is said that he who does not remember the past is condemned to
repeat it.
Commentaries on India’s current growth slowdown are very similar
to those that appeared after the slowdown of the late nineties.
Then too, it was said India was incapable of growing at a higher
rate; the slowdown had basically reverted growth to its ‘true’ lower trend.
Now, it is being said the higher growth that followed from 2003 to
2010 was an unsustainable aberration caused by the global boom and excess
liquidity flows to emerging economies. The critics of this view, in turn, hold
that the current slowdown being experienced by India has to do with internal
problems, and not any global shocks.
Either way, they show the infeasibility of higher growth!
HISTORICAL CYCLES
But the fact is even in a slowdown, the growth rates in India
today exceed the earlier so-called Hindu rate of growth of 3.5 per cent or so.
While the volatility of growth has, no doubt, increased after the reforms,
post-Independence growth cycles still have similarities. Understanding these is
educative.
India’s slowdowns have been triggered mainly by supply shocks. In
the early years, these were largely on account of monsoon failures, which used
to lead to large government spending. Since the Reserve Bank of India was then
obliged to automatically finance government deficits, this spending used to be
accommodated. But that would usually be followed by a severe tightening, thereby
hitting industry just as input prices tended to rise.
Something similar happened as oil price shocks became important,
from the 1970s onwards. Since the increases in global oil price were not
immediately passed through to consumers, government deficits would rise and
these would be monetised. At the same time, private spending would be squeezed,
while the period of monetary tightening that followed would also be used for
some pass-through of oil prices.
So, costs would rise for industry, just when demand fell.
What these types of supply shocks did was raise costs at all
levels of production, even though firms continued or may have continued to have
excess capacity.
The supply shocks, in other words, would shift up or to the left
an elastic supply curve, rather than shift to the left an inelastic supply
curve.
POST-REFORM CYCLES
Economic liberalisation and reforms stopped automatic
monetisation, forcing the Government to borrow at market rates. Investment, too,
was now largely a private sector activity, as growing deficits, poor returns
from past investments, and pre-emption of expenditures by subsidies and other
recurrent spending reduced public investment. Simultaneously, the growing share
of retail and housing loans increased the sensitivity of consumption to interest
rates. As a result, growth and investment became doubly sensitive to these
rates.
Interest rates were gradually freed, but in thin money markets,
proved to be volatile. In the late nineties, as capital flowed out after the
East Asian currency crisis, a liquidity squeeze, aggravated by sharp increases
in policy rates, resulted in high and sticky loan rates.
The investment cycle collapsed and took five years to recover, the
impetus for which came from softening global interest rates and an effective
public road building programme.
At the same time, since overcapacities tend to get built up during
booms, it makes private investment inherently volatile. In the latest boom
phase, loan rate volatility was somewhat reduced because of improved
articulation of market segments. Also, maturing of institutions such as the
liquidity adjustment facility allowed more policy fine-tuning in response to
shocks.
But volatility in interest rates still came from large corrections
in policy rates due to the unprecedented shocks associated with the global
financial crisis of 2008. The same crisis was also preceded by a sharp rise in
world food and oil prices — canonical supply shocks in the Indian context.
The Government responded to the 2008 crisis by reversing fiscal
consolidation to create a fiscal stimulus after global export and domestic
private demand fell.
But government-supported expenditures also raised the demand for
food, whose prices were already high, even as restrictions of various types on
farm trade prevented an appropriate supply response.
Also, increased risk aversion on the part of overseas investors
from the euro crisis led to forex outflows, putting pressure on the rupee and
raising the price of imports. The cumulative impact of all this was that demand
fell for industry as rates rose, just as input costs rose. This, plus the excess
capacity built in the previous boom, inhibited fresh investments. Problems in
land acquisition and in the allocation of other natural resources only
compounded the situation, affecting investments in infrastructure and adding to
the supply bottlenecks in the economy.
Thus, we have all the components of pre-reform growth slowdowns in
the current episode — high food and oil prices, large fiscal deficits, and
demand squeeze on industry. The difference is that the demand squeeze has come
now predominantly through interest rates.
It is regarded as a puzzle that despite low industrial growth and
excess capacity for a year, core inflation remains above 5 per cent. But costs
are high and mark-ups on costs are often countercyclical — these being raised to
spread fixed costs when capacity utilisation is low.
POLICY FINE-TUNING
It is possible to target policy properly to match the structure of
the slowdown. The administrative hurdles that restrict investment, especially in
areas where there are shortages, must be lifted. The composition of Government
expenditure, too, must change from creating demand in sectors where increase in
supply is disabled, to releasing supply bottlenecks.
Critical and focused action in these directions is the type of
countercyclical policy that is feasible and could be effective. As costs and
inflation come down, falling interest rates would provide further boost to
recovery.
India’s potential rate of growth has risen, but the correct policy
combination required for stabilisation of business cycles has not been
implemented.
(The author is Professor of Economics. IGIDR, Mumbai.
No comments:
Post a Comment